Could College Be Cheaper?

Like Fontana Labs, I’ve long fretted that some day, all at once, in a tipping point reaction, both employers and families are going to decide in two different directions that expensive college degrees no longer predict success strongly and are not worth pursuing regardless of whatever usefulness they may or may not have.

There are reasons why that might not happen. For one, I think many colleges and universities are educating their students productively. The sky might not be falling so much as some people think it is. For another, the more highly selective a college or university is in its admission policies, the more useful it is for an employer as a device for identifying potentially valuable employees, even if the employer doesn’t know or care what happened to the potential employee while he or she was a student. If so, this has bad implications for expensive noncompetitive lower-tier private colleges, possibly, but since they’ve long since been the most economically tenuous part of the higher education sector, that’s not news. Also, it’s fairly hard to imagine what employers with relatively high turnover and thus a need for constantly refreshing their supply of lower-management employees would do to process their applicant pools if they didn’t have a B.A. degree as a basic screening device. Finally, the fact that public schools are becoming much more expensive in a way benefits the entire higher education sector in terms of its ability to sustain high prices for the long-term future. It used to be that you could get an education at some of the major public universities that rivalled most major private universities and at a much cheaper price. That’s increasingly no longer the case, so anybody who is fed up with the cost really has nowhere to turn besides not doing it at all.

Let’s suppose, however, that there is a tipping point out there somewhere, that higher education is moving towards a collective calamity in its pricing. What would it take for colleges and universities to start reducing their costs and lowering the price? For one, many institutions would have to do it at the same time. That’s because lowering the price is going to involve shucking off at least some of the product being made available. Doing that unilaterally is likely to be suicidal, especially among the top-end institutions. How to coordinate that movement without running afoul of antitrust collusion is a big issue in its own right.

The important thing is that parents and other observers have to understand that the high cost is in fact buying a wide range of services. Anybody who thinks you can shave the cost appreciably with little gestures of economy doesn’t understand the basic structure of academic budgets. Moreover, some of the most powerful external costs driving up academic budgets cannot be affected appreciably by colleges and universities acting on their own, but only by some larger public policy. Insurance, for example, or the costs of health care. The only thing universities could do on either of those is reduce the amount of insurance they carry or their benefits, and in many cases, those benefits already compare unfavorably to both the private sector and even to other non-profits. In other cases, costs could be controlled by universities, for example, in libraries, but only by changing the nature of academic publishing and academic credentialling, which will require faculties to participate in major reform initiatives.

What could a given university do that would not require collective action of this kind? Here I’ll cannibalize some of my observations from 21st Century College. A college or university could stop providing services of various kinds. For example, no health care for undergraduates. No counseling or help with student life issues. No athletic facilities or student life facilities. Minimalist classrooms, with minimal technological support save that which is paid for by external grants or support. Subcontract out all food services and other amenities to the highest bidders; manage nothing of this kind directly. Shed any services which do not relate to core instruction. Build only when buildings are about to literally fall apart; build nothing else unless it is completely paid for by external funding including a maintenance endowment.

You could radically intervene in the curriculum to throw overboard areas which do not pay for themselves through external grants, or which have low enrollments. You could make extensive use of adjunct or contract faculty (an already preferred solution, and thus unlikely to produce even more extensive savings.)

In fact, quite a bit of this on the curricular side is already being done at many institutions, and is the source of some complaints about the “corporatization” of universities. On the services side, however, there is largely still only growth and expansion. However, that’s in substantial measure because that’s what the paying customers want. A cheaper university sounds great until you add that it would also be a no-frills university with virtually no services, and then I suspect quite a few parents and students might feel differently. Moreover, such a university would undoubtedly be massively exposed to liability as well as discord: many of the services added in the last fifteen years are direct responses to lawsuits or agitation by students and other constituents.

The cost of higher education worries me enormously. It appears unsustainable as well as unjust. It is aggravating a problem that is somewhat separate in its causal underpinnings, the increasing degree to which universities are exacerbating the reduction of economic and social mobility in the United States. But I’m not sure what to do about it. I think at the least that some of the people most aggravated about it are going to need to get real about what it is that they’re asking for: curricula that are pared down radically to what external funders judge valuable and thus heavily biased to technical subjects with immediate professional payoffs, and institutions with few if any meaningful services beyond education. It would be interesting, at any rate, to see an institution of higher learning built on those principles start up in this marketplace, at least one that wasn’t built around online education, and see how it fares (and just how low it could get tuition).

Posted in Academia | 18 Comments

Tenure

I’m with Brad DeLong: John Tierney’s column on cronyism and academia is an especially annoying case of the lack-of-pluralism-in-academia argument. It is a lazy conflation of two completely different issues. I’m perfectly willing to agree that there is a problem with a lack of intellectual pluralism in many parts of the academy, but for reasons which have nothing to do with the concept of cronyism that’s being applied to the Miers nomination.

In fact, the situation in academia is often almost the opposite. A distant relation of mine had worked in the past in the Swarthmore administration before I got hired here: we’ve joked occasionally since that it’s a damn good thing he didn’t know I was up for the job until I got it and that no one knew of the relationship. Trading on connections in most academic institutions, at least since the mid-1970s, is done with extreme delicacy if at all. Your advisor or pedigree or influential patrons may help you find a job in some contexts, but only if their influence is exerted with extreme passivity and indirection. They may equally hurt you: I can think of some important patrons in some disciplines whose students have sometimes suffered the brunt of professional jealousy directed at their teachers while on the job market. If administrations at universities or colleges try to intervene in hiring processes directly, they often end up causing faculty to move in the opposite direction just to spite the administration.

Groupthink and insularity in academia mostly don’t come from cronyism or nepotism, from anti-meritocratic promotions designed to reward personal loyalty to a powerful figure. When that sort of thing does happen within a single institution, it tends to spawn enormous ill-will and backlash, and it tends to be connected to the kinds of total failures of leadership of the sort exhibited by John Silber at Boston University.

Academic insularity comes from collective institutions and passive-aggressive models of distributed enforcement of the sort exemplified in tenure decisions. There’s been a lot of talk about tenure in the last week among bloggers due to Daniel Drezner’s denial of tenure. I thought Sean McCann’s comments on the case were among the best I’d seen. In particular, Sean captured my own dual reaction: dismay at the decision, a creeping sense that it connected to what I see as some of the underlying problems with academia’s overspecialization and insularity, but also irritation with some of the rather Tierney-like pronouncements about the decision, which often demonstrated little knowledge of academic institutions and their internal governance.

As long as tenure exists, for example, it’s never going to be easy to exercise it with any selectivity. The number of people who make it through the numbing process of graduate school who are blatantly unqualified to be scholars or ignorant are perishingly small. If that’s all that you eliminated in granting lifetime employment, you’d have to abandon any sense that tenure ought to be about a serious appraisal of scholarly potential and teaching ability. Many smart academics could potentially write a blog rather like Dan Drezner’s: it is not what he writes per se in his blog that is an indication of his distinctive quality as an intellectual, but that he wrote it in a situation where it was potentially career-threatening to do so, and certainly not career-enhancing. That indicates a clarity of commitment to the public character of scholarly work and to the communicative ability that is one of the foundations of good teaching.

But institutions have their own cultures, too, which is what perhaps the non-academic readers can’t or don’t perceive. What gets you tenure at Harvard is not what gets you tenure at Swarthmore which is not what gets you tenure at the University of Alabama. Perhaps that is not as it should be: I’ve said many times that I think Harvard’s approach is devastatingly self-destructive, and that goes for Chicago as well. What one is complaining about, however, in attacking the way tenure works within these specific institutional cultures and across academia as a whole is not something like cronyism. It’s about administrative structures like departments, about the premium that the organization of academic places on inward-turning specialization, about modes of achievement that often rest on bygone publishing regimes and practices of readership which have no more than a decade’s worth of life left to them. It’s also about peculiarly local cultures of institutional life that really need to be appreciated in their own terms before understanding how and why they’re misfiring in the way that they sometimes do.

There is a lot wrong with this whole way of running the railroad, but tenure is really only a symptom of that deeper disorder. In fact, abolishing tenure would not, as Sean McCann notes, really improve things. Any departmentalized, specialized, decentralized academic institution would shoot itself in the foot just as effectively with multiyear contracts as lifetime tenure, only more often and with greater chaos. Any highly centralized, bureaucratized, top-down controlled campus would have opposite but equally bad problems, becoming more like the immobile and unproductive institutions that dot the landscape in Western Europe.

The problem in a way is that American universities and colleges don’t, can’t, think in any centralized way about what allows them to function well, what maximizes their internal productivity and generativity.

Some of it is the result of very deep-seated internal contradictions about what kinds of productivity is meant: productivity of knowledge, of engagement with the world, of numbers of “student units” churned out, of reputation?

More of the problem is that the consumers of higher education and its products (whether students, employers or the public sphere) don’t really know how to evaluate the relationship between external reputation and internal process (something that some of the discussion of Drezner’s case illustrates). They don’t know what goes on inside a university, or what it is that faculty do.

Take my day today. It’s fall break here. I worked on a book chapter on my book about Zimbabwe and chiefship this morning. I did a quick-edit of an article for an online journal in games studies after that. I replied to a lot of email. I talked to a reporter. I worked on this blog entry. I answered a survey on using digital images in the classroom. I prepared some material for use in courses next week. I read some of the texts I’m teaching from next week. I tried to arrange a lunch for a visiting colleague who is coming to give a talk on Monday. I began to prepare my book orders for next semester. I looked over a report on a recent conference that’s going to quote some of what I said in emails and thought about how to edit down what I’d said informally so the insulting stuff stayed off the record. I did some planning for a visit from a speaker on Monday Oct. 24th that turns out to have a hidden logistical problem. I worked a bit on a proposed “decision rule” for a planning committee on I’m on. I talked with a friend about a workshop on fieldwork that we’ve organized in New York City tomorrow, and how we want to substantively organize the discussion. I read some of the material he circulated for the workshop. I did a bit of thinking about a presentation I did earlier in the week for an alumni reading group and some substantive questions to circulate in early November when the reading groups begin meeting actively.

That’s a pretty busy day, partially because I’m using my break to catch up on some of that stuff, but it’s reasonably typical of the balls I’m juggling in the air most semesters. It is a typical example of how contemporary academics are producing knowledge, teaching and acting as administrators all at once. Some colleagues do as much or more than I do; some do less. It is so at most universities and colleges. But I don’t think outsiders have any sense of that work process, and they certainly don’t evaluate academic institutions on whether or how any of that is getting done, or getting done well. Because they don’t, because the reputation of academic institutions is mostly not especially dependent on what faculty actually do or don’t do, academics themselves don’t have to think carefully about any of this when they think about tenure or hiring or promotion or training of graduate students. A business thinks (or should) about who is a “value-added” employee; academia instead mystfies and obscures its own work processes, works its reputation capital in ways that often don’t come back to the actual engines of productivity, and reproduces itself in ways that often maximize insularity and dysfunction rather than make an effective connection between institutional generativity and social capital in the world at large. There are no reputational consequences in many cases for institutions which suffer badly from internal disorder or poor institutional productivity, and few reputational benefits from the opposite. That also goes for individual faculty. Dan Drezner’s blog is a “value-added” asset for the University of Chicago (or was until he was denied tenure) but most of us know, including Dan, that it was never likely to be accredited as such.

Complain about that if you like: I will endorse your complaint. Suggest it may be an issue in Drezner’s case, or many other cases, and you may be correct. But whatever it is, it’s not cronyism. That’s somebody else’s problem, somebody else’s failure, and it is the height of anti-intellectual laziness to trot out and try to blame the eggheads for that, too, on top of all the things that they already have a problem with.

Posted in Academia | 5 Comments

Serious Fun

Though it put me into a serious week-long hustle to catch up on all sorts of work (hence the paucity of entries here lately), Edward Castronova’s Ludium conference at Indiana University’s Center for the Study of Synthetic Worlds was easily the most interesting academic meeting I’ve been to in years.

The conference was structured by dividing the participants up into five teams, each of which was composed of visiting academics from a number of disciplines, executives and programmers from the computer games industry, and local Indiana University faculty. The basic structure of the meeting was that each group was tasked in a series of time-constrained “games” to construct interesting, viable, affordable proposals for research projects using synthetic or virtual worlds, culminating in a major proposal from each group.

Nothing was at stake except pride, though put enough people with an interest in games, play and computing together in a setting like this one and you can bet they’ll take anything labelled as a “game” pretty seriously, which in fact by and large the participants did. But the results certainly beat listening to a bunch of people read 25-page papers in a monotone, or for that matter, watching a canned PowerPoint presentation where the presenter reads each bullet point verbatim as it crosses the screen. There was a lot of intellectual gravity to the deliberations, but also a good deal of spontaneous creativity and fun. The collaborative structure also kept the academics from burdening the industry participants with irrelevantly monastic scholasticism while also keeping the programmers and executives from constraining the results to pure marketability and practicality.

It might seem that the structure of the meeting could only work for this kind of topic, but having thought about it for a week, I think any professional meeting or workshop could benefit from having some content that was “short-term collaborative”, that was aimed at spontaneous, speculative discussion. For example, imagine a meeting of the American Historical Association where five small workshop groups of historians (from grad students to senior professors) had to brainstorm a list of the ten most influential works of social history and then submit their list to a voting audience to determine the most authoritative or interesting list. I’m just thinking here off the top of my head, but I can see the possibilities, as long as you could find a way to keep the participants from getting overly defensive about turf issues or prestige.

I’m also increasingly enamored of trying to teach with these kinds of exercises as a major part of what I ask students to do. If I think about the usual kind of final exam, the alleged virtue of having students take a timed exam is supposedly to test their abilities to deploy remembered concrete knowledge in a time-constrained context. I really wonder more and more if an essay question is the best way to do that. One of the amazing things for me at the Ludium meeting was watching the speed and clarity of the way the industry participants tended to think about problems, and how quickly they wrestled difficult issues into some kind of concrete and clearly communicable form. If students at an institution like Swarthmore learn how to do the same, at least in the humanities, it’s often going to be entirely on their own, outside of their courses. But there’s no reason why that should be: we could easily be trying to get students to tap into that set of skills, and evaluating them on their performance. The only problem is that it would take us being able to teach and appreciate such skills, and I’m not sure that all that many scholars in the humanities here or elsewhere are prepared to do so.

Posted in Academia, Games and Gaming | 9 Comments

How Many Bad Apples Before You Blame the Farmer?

Human Rights Watch has a new report on the widespread torturing of Iraqi detainees by US forces from 2003-2004.

I’ll be curious to hear the explanations, excuses, alibis from defenders of the war. Probably quite a few will try to kill the report through a thousand quibbles. I suspect many of them are just going to drop the pretense that this is isolated misconduct and try to actually justify it, either as the result of the understandable emotional reaction of US troops (which, you know, is why countries committed to human rights normally take formal steps to safeguard the rights of prisoners of all kinds, precisely because we understand that there will be a temptation) or even as a legitimate tactic of counterinsurgency.

Given that this was contemporaneous with Abu Ghraib, it’s also possible that some of this misconduct has ended or been checked. I’m fully prepared to hear convincing evidence to this effect. But that it happened at all, and on this scale, is a devastating blow to not just the war in Iraq, but the overall legitimacy and credibility of the United States in pursuit of its declared objectives in the “war on terror”. So if you care about that war in any way, or about the specific theater of Iraq, there’s really only one legitimate response to allegations like these: take them seriously, be gravely disturbed by them, demand that the people responsible (including at the very top, in the Administration) be held responsible–and ask yourself what it would take for the war you defend to be fought in terms which are a credit to the best of America’s possibilities. If you evade, doubletalk, or worse of all, legitimize, when confronted with this sort of evidence, you’re no defender of the struggle against terrorism, no defender of the global aspiration for freedom: you’re on the other side.

Posted in Politics | 28 Comments

Caiman on the Crum

Well, that was a different sort of story to read in the local newspaper. A four-and-a-half foot caiman was found by the cops in the little creek that runs below the college, about a half-mile south of the college. They even had pictures: not an urban legend. Just as long as they don’t find my pet sasquatch I’m hiding in the woods down there, I guess.

Posted in Miscellany | 2 Comments

Choose Your Own Adventure

When you read a number of blogs, you get to a point where you know very well which articles in the mainstream media, especially the New York Times, are going to spawn a frenzied discussion. Then it’s primarily a question of which writer’s initial take is going to shape the debate at its outset.

This time it’s Kieran Healy who kicked it off at Crooked Timber, responding to a NY Times article that suggested that increasing numbers of women at elite universities are primarily envisioning their future in terms of a periodic engagement with the professional job market interspaced with a concentrated period of child-rearing, rather than thinking first and foremost about the most ambitious career trajectory possible and deferring questions about family life.

Kieran complains that this article concedes too much to an ideology of individuation, that we’re being manipulated to respond (and many in the Crooked Timber message threads do) by second-guessing the women’s choices. I actually think Kieran does that himself, though he protests that it’s not really his main point or intent. For Kieran, the real question is a wider social issue about the balance between work and family, and the unjust extent to which the professional classes have choices that the rest of American society does not, because we make no guarantee or provision for opening that choice to anyone but the professional elite.

The problem is that this is a complaint about the entire existence or social condition of the professional class, which I suspect Kieran might cop to. There’s no reason why it should be contained to the work/family problem. There’s no distinction in this sense between an undergraduate who says to me, “I intend to concentrate primarily on child-rearing when the time comes that I have a child, and to do what’s necessary in preparation for that” and an undergraduate who says to me, “I intend to look for a small community where I can find a comfortable and relaxed career path outside of the mainstream” or the one who says, “I intend to live on a lesbian commune in Vermont and grow organic vegetables” or the one who says, “I plan to find a studio in a cheaper city, set up a small loft in the back, minimize my expenses so I can live off my small trust fund and explore my artistic interests”.

Every single one of those plans may run into unexpected real-world difficulties. Every single one of them is a sign of the luxuriousness of being part of the professional class educated at an elite college, of a condition of choice which is unevenly and inequitably distributed that an elite university education exacerbates rather than corrects at the scale of society as a whole. The only reason to react differentially to the women in the NY Times article is in the context of a prescriptive feminist argument about women’s roles and social pressure or a claim that these women are “free-riders” on feminist achievements, precisely the response that Kieran mostly wants to forego in favor of a broader social critique. The broader critique can’t distinguish between the women quoted in the article and any undergraduate at any elite educational institution imagining that they will choose to forego maximizing their income in favor of maximizing other forms of satisfaction and self-realization.

The only meaningfully specific response that I think you can have to the article is about feminism, gender roles, equality and intergenerational values within the professional classes, and here I do think that these women are betraying an awareness of the costs that an ideology of heroic womanhood has imposed on the generation that came before them, and preemptively deciding to avoid that trap. (They may also have a callow lack of awareness of the historical preconditions that have made this a choice rather than a commandment.) They may find themselves in another trap: no generation is likely to find personal utopia just by laying better plans down at age 22. This is the only profitable debate I think relates directly to the content of the article. I don’t see that debate as a distraction or red herring as Kieran does. It may make sense in other contexts to pose this as being about privilege and choice, but that’s a bigger and wider discussion.

Choosing is what the graduates of elite universities and colleges do, period. It is what we commonly urge our students to do, what we promise to them, how we pitch the value of the liberal arts. We efface the directness of a connection between professional ambition (and projected incomes) and the content of a liberal arts education. We talk about the flexibility of critical thought, that it can enhance anything and everything in life: career, family life, individual character. We talk about the realization of a condition of choice.

I think that’s right and proper (here I am echoing some of Margaret Soltan’s take on the issue.) Not just because it’s a good marketing hook, but because it’s the only thing that keeps a liberal arts education from just being a cold-cash transaction, a cynically concocted and cynically desired ticket to a professional class identity, an education whose content or quality doesn’t especially matter. Well, ok, that’s a Harvard undergraduate education, but it isn’t or shouldn’t be what most elite educational institutions are offering. I believe in what we’re doing, and believe that it’s about both concrete skills that have a practical and applied payoff and about values, character and the cultivation of self. Of course that’s a mark of privilege: but we should continue to do it anyway, and believe in doing it. I can’t stand it when my students come to me and start flagellating themselves because they want to live a satisfying life full of deeply personal meaning but woe is me for wanting to make that choice it is so very wrong and unequal I am so privileged I am not worthy forgive me for I am a sinner blah blah blah.

If one group of young women work through what a college or university sets in front of them and decide that they’re going to choose to invest themselves in a life course where family comes first and work comes second, and their status as certified members of the professional classes is what makes that possible, that is not different in kind from the student who wants to be a performance artist or the student who wants to do development work for Oxfam or the student who wants to be a small-town doctor in northern Idaho. It’s only different in substance, and so the only real immediate discussion about whether we want to second-guess (or applaud) this particular substantive choice in the particular terms it presents.

Addendum: I think you can also respond profitably to the article by suggesting that this is more of the NY Times’ typical tendency to assume that a trend they can locate in a very particular subset of a very particular social class is somehow a general social indicator of some kind, that this is just a Brooks-style bit of anecdotal fluff posing as a trend. But ok. That’s almost by definition a diss on all lifestyle journalism, or all claims about trends that don’t come packing major sociological data. Not much to discuss about this observation, though: one simply makes it, sniffs, and walks away.

Posted in Academia, Politics | 15 Comments

High Camp

So we were thinking a bit of going camping this weekend. I used to backpack in the Sierras with my family when I was a kid, haven’t really done anything like it as an adult, just a lot of day hiking. My wife’s never slept in a tent ever, and obviously, neither has the four-year old. I was thinking of something easy, like driving down to Cape Henlopen in Delaware, right near the beach, with a tent, some sleeping bags, some supplies, and our dog. A water hookup would be nice, but not required.

Cape Henlopen and another nearby Delaware state park turn out to be fully booked for the coming weekend and have been for a while: some kind of race event or something is going on. So I’ve been looking around for other places on the shore. There’s a state park in New Jersey along the shore that has tent campsites, but right now they’re not allowing any fires at all of any kind anywhere, including barbecues. Ok, that sucks. Every other search I’ve done for New Jersey’s shore areas has turned up these gi-normous RV-centric places where they’ve got swimming pools, hideous-sounding group activities and so on: basically they are RV resorts that also have some tent sites. Not what I have in mind when it comes to pitching a tent in a quiet outdoors area, especially since if I’m gonna camp on the shore, I want to be pretty much almost at the beach, as you are at Cape Henlopen, not in some wooded area where I have to hop in a car to get to the beach. These places basically sound like motels without the motel. If I’m going to stay in a motel at a cheap resort, I’m gonna stay at a motel at a cheap resort, not pitch a tent.

So getting a bit desperate, I look as far afield as southern Maryland, Assateague Island and Janes Island, though it’s a really long haul from here to there. I’ve been to Assateague before, it’s nice. Whoops, that’s booked too. Janes has some openings. But then I also notice that Assateague and Janes both have a really strict no-pets anywhere in the state park policy, so much for taking the nice doggie along.

Am I missing something? Is there a great fairly quiet, outdoors, tent-centric shore camping area in New Jersey or Delaware that allows dogs and fires? Is this a freakish ambition?

Posted in Miscellany | 8 Comments

You Can’t Shoot Someone Online

…but boy, do I understand why someone in a 19th Century Wild West saloon might have reached for the hidden gun in their boots to blow someone away after a hand of [online] poker.

I say this after having gone all in on the button with a flopped pair of kings and a queen kicker, having successfully gotten all but one person to fold with that play. Said person was holding an unsuited 8 2, nothing in the flop. On the turn they got an 8, on the river they got a 2. It is my opinion that in a just world in which God exists He should strike that person on the head with a large rock at that point, both because they had no business calling with an unsuited 8 2 on a flop with a K in it (let alone playing the 8 2 in the first place) and even less business actually getting the two running cards to win. I normally hate it when people bitch about somebody else hitting a hand on the river, but this is something on an entirely different level of cosmic injustice.

Posted in Miscellany | 8 Comments

As Long As I’m At It…

Ok, so I’ve suggested to the American Historical Association (AHA) that they should eliminate formal paper sessions with extreme prejudice. That goes for all big professional meetings (MLA, AAA, what have you): no more formal paper sessions in which participants take 15-20 minutes to read a paper, ever. The intellectual content of big professional meetings should be more like blogging, frankly: roundtable responses to current issues in the discipline. Roundtables on controversial books, on the discipline’s encounters with the public sphere, on major internal disputes within the discipline, and so on. The kind of thing that doesn’t get talked about except between the lines in the ordinary business of scholarly publication. Papers or formal writings are for small, concentrated, topically focused meetings.

Next on the chopping block: any pretense by professional associations to exert leadership over a discipline. On the issues where that leadership might actually matter in internal terms, such as sanctioning practicioners for misconduct like plagiarism, the big associations routinely duck, avoid or explicitly abjure an active stance. That’s probably a sound legal strategy, and may even be a sage admission of the necessary limits of the association’s capacity. Often when disciplinary associations try to address the deeper flaws inherent in contemporary academic practice (say the overproduction of doctorates in the field, or the misuse of adjunct instructors), they either come off like a butcher trying to perform brain surgery with a hatchet, or they offer hopelessly meek, mealy-mouthed, everybody’s-got-a-point responses that do nothing to address the situation but also convince onlookers of the inability of academics to police themselves.

What annoys me more is when any of the disciplinary associations attempt to take a position on behalf of the discipline on significant public or political issues. Not because I’m apolitical, or even because I disagree with the positions taken, but because the associations usually have no basis for exerting meaningful clout, because they’re inevitably amateurs playing a game dominated by hardcore professionals, because they frequently end up making the professoriate look worse in the public eye in the process, and because this often leads to wasting money on payments to lobbyists or consultants who are content to spin some wheels and look busy.

I’m not always sure I want my professional associations taking positions on issues that are legitimately and narrowly within their domain (say, the AHA on K-12 history curricula in U.S. schools, or the African Studies Association on Title VI funding for African studies) but at least that makes good sense, and often has productive results.

What else? Drop any association journals that aren’t established, prestigious outlets for publication in the discipline. The American Historical Review is an established, prestigious journal: the AHA ought to keep that. However, plenty of professional associations, especially the smaller specialized ones, churn out weak journal-type publications that probably end up in the garbage of many members. Kill vanity publication lines, or well-meaning but pointlessly tree-killing pamphlets that are meant to communicate some worthy but self-evident sentiment to members or to audiences that well-meaning members think ought to be the targets of some sort of outreach.

On the other hand, constantly data-mine the membership for the kind of information that we’re constantly thinking about in the administrative side of faculty jobs: what the distribution of specializations in the discipline is, what the current demographics of the discipline are, what the average size of departments in the discipline are (on a kind of “per capita” level, in comparison to other departments at institutions), what the ratio of people trained to people finding tenure-track jobs in the discipline is. Track what Brian Leiter tracks for philosophy (what Lingua Franca used to track for everybody): major movements of personnel in the discipline at the senior level, and hires at the junior level. There are a lot of times where it would be useful for me to be able to make definitive statements about whether history as a discipline is growing or shrinking, what the current balance of specializations actually is and how it has changed over ten years, and so on. None of this matters, however, unless you make this information available quickly and regularly to the membership.

Every professional association should have an active web presence, maybe even a blog or two. That’s where the data being collected constantly could be published, just as regularly. You should be able to renew your membership and deal with all other membership details quickly and painlessly online. The way some professional associations come at it, you’d think maintaining an online presence of this kind is a daunting technical challenge that has to be custom-designed from the ground up. Or alternatively, that it’s some amateur thing to hack out over the weekend.

The problem with trying to make any of these suggestions beyond a quickly-dashed-off blog entry, of course, is that you’ll inevitably end up asked to sit on an associational committee or worse yet, told to run for an associational office if you care that much. I don’t care that much, so I have no interest in going beyond blog-kibitzing.

Posted in Academia | 31 Comments

On Dreams

This morning my 4-year old daughter Emma reported that she had a nightmare last night. We’ve talked a bit about nightmares, I’ve told her how I used to have really bad ones at her age. She asked me what dreams I had last night. I couldn’t remember any specifically.

The professor-voice took over and I started to explain that dreams are a way your brain sorts through its experiences and organizes them.

Emma interrupts the dry explanation with a useful metaphor: “…So your brain is like the kids at school putting away toys after playtime”.

Me: “Yeah! Exactly!”

Emma: “And it’s like your brain decides to turn on the TV set while it puts away the toys.”

Me: “So, your neurobiology classes at preschool are going well! That’s great!”

Posted in Miscellany | 3 Comments