Playing Reindeer Games

In her op-ed on Robert Mugabe, Heidi Holland portrays him partially as a wayward child of Western civilization who has his nose pressed against the glass, hoping to be invited back in from the cold from whence his “heathen granny” came. In her interview with him, Holland writes, Mugabe “expressed almost tearful regret at his inability to socialize with the Queen of England”.

It’s easy to laugh this portrait off as a product of Holland’s own naivete. I know that I no longer accept the view that Mugabe was once committed to national reconciliation after 1980 and somehow lost that commitment along the way, a trope that Holland recycles in her essay. Looking back, what I see instead is Mugabe’s typically hard-nosed assessment of the power available to him at the time. He and the core of his party needed time to gain control of the mechanisms of the state they had inherited, to consolidate national power. I do not think it was an accident that he turned on rival nationalists before dealing with other potential opponents, including the white farmers, trade unionists and the tattered remnants of a liberal civil society that the Rhodesians had done their best to destroy before Mugabe ever took power. I think the Mugabe who ruthlessly took control of his own party before independence, stalled with reconciliation tactics after independence, and flushed his nation’s economy down the toilet are pretty much the same person, acting with similar underlying impulses in all those situations.

That said, I think Holland is also right that he wants the respect of the West and inclusion within the contours of what colonial society in Africa defined as “civilization”. Mugabe has put his personal stamp on this desire: the steely Jesuitical temperment, the fastidiousness and relative minimalism of his public presentation, the building of a strong state apparatus that centers on his personal authority but is not reducible to a cult of personality. (Whatever else its problems might be, Zimbabwe does not suffer from a failure of state capacity or a weak sovereignty: the state has real, persistent power throughout most of its territory, very much including a monopoly on violence.) He doesn’t exhibit the romantic Europhilia of Leopold Senghor, or the eccentric Homburg-wearing hippiephobia of Hastings Banda. Mugabe doesn’t indulge in the kid-in-the-candy-store splurges of the most vulgar of postcolonial African leaders (though he has plenty of ill-gotten gains from his time in power), or hanker to build a reputation for being a reliable subscriber to the Washington Consensus like Museveni or Rowlings, so as to get an invitation or two to Davos from time to time.

One of the basic problems in studying modern African history is that African experience is most copiously represented back to knowledge-making by people who were the most transformed by colonial rule and the most conflicted about that transformation. In some ways, this is the same reason that identity politics within Western societies often finds its most tenacious adherents not among the most marginal or excluded subjects but among middle classes and aspirants who are both trying to preserve fragile and hard-won access to professional or bourgeois life and secure further pathways for aspiration through arguments about identity, history and social justice.

Just observing that African nationalist politics came into being out of frustration and rage by nationalist elites or evolues at their racially-based exclusion from the ranks of “civilized men” is not a critique. It’s boring and simple-minded to write this history off as hypocrisy or contradiction. However, African nationalism has tended to regard such an analysis as an attack precisely because its usual mythological reinventions after post-independence consolidations of power describe African nation-states as the product of the massification of nationalism in the march to independence. Calling attention to the social history of African nationalism, its historical particularism, is a rebuke to African nationalism’s ideology whether we wish to make that rebuke or not.

Scorning or mocking the nationalist’s earnest desire for inclusion in some aspect of the “civilizing mission” is just another kind of hating the hybrid, the cosmopolitan, the miscegenated, the “man of two worlds”. Mugabe is not distinguished from other African elites, or modern political classes in general, in his desire to be taken seriously by Queen Elizabeth and Tony Blair, to be authenticated not just as a been-to but a have-become. When Chief Munhuwepayi Mangwende was deposed by the Rhodesian government in 1960, at least one of the reasons was the bitter jealousy of a local white district officer who resented that the chief had access to high British society while the white bureaucrat did not.

One of the most interesting things I’ve ever read in an archive is a letter from David Gurupira to the Chief Native Commissioner of Southern Rhodesia in 1938. As I read it, Gurupira isn’t a simple collaborator, motivated by calculating self-interest. Instead, I think he’s someone who has assessed and imagined aspects of the colonizer’s world and power and wants to selectively include himself within some of what he envisions it to be. He hasn’t lost himself, or forgotten his history. His mind hasn’t been colonized. He isn’t slavish or empty. The officials who received his letter were not the imperial buffoons that we often see in stereotypical accounts, either. They understood what Gurupira was saying: “his facts are substantially correct”. The tragedy of colonialism is that they could only offer to him the right to bear arms, rather than acknowledge his claims or open up their own power to his gentle demands.

This might sound as if I’m agreeing with Holland that the West need only embrace Mugabe and give him his due, invite him into the social apparatus of global power, grant him the cultural capital to which he is entitled. By no means. When we condemn Mugabe harshly, when we make of him a pariah, we are including him. The most condescending, exclusionary option would be to pat him on the head like a good little non-Westerner and say, “Well, he doesn’t know any better, the little tyke. He can’t help being an authoritarian. Besides, isn’t it our own fault anyway that he is? We did promise to help out with land reform, chaps.” As long as we’re even-handed in demanding liberty everywhere always, as long as we don’t hold Mugabe accountable for actions that are forgiven of reliable authoritarian clients, as long as we don’t excuse fraud, corruption, cronyism and the concentration of unaccountable executive power when it is expedient for our own purposes, then the harshest attacks on Mugabe’s conduct as a political leader are just as welcoming as a royal reception with Queen Elizabeth II.

Posted in Africa, Politics | 8 Comments

The Ministers for Omnipotent Ruritania Offer You a Deal

I had two separate reactions to Heidi Holland’s op-ed about Robert Mugabe, so I’ll blog about it twice.

Holland argues that Western nations should make peace with Robert Mugabe, partly on the grounds that a punitive approach has accomplished nothing and left no avenues for wheedling or persuading Mugabe to act differently than he does. On one level, this is just the old merry-go-round of sanctions or shunning versus “constructive engagement” taking another spin. That’s an argument that I find bitterly futile when it’s voiced in terms of absolutes: it is always a situational question. I find Holland’s take on Mugabe accurate enough (that’s my other reaction, see the next essay), but I don’t think that a sympathetic or constructive approach to Mugabe is any more likely to persuade him to do the right thing.

On a deeper level, though, Holland’s argument makes me think about another class of interminable debates about how outside powers should construct incentives that encourage authoritarians to give up power and discourage kleptocrats from robbing their own countries blind. In Zimbabwe, the MDC has started offering assurances to military leaders that they will not be prosecuted for their actions under the Mugabe regime, and that the MDC will not confiscate property they may have acquired in the last decade except under pre-1997 rules of land reform. Before the general seizure of commercial farms, the Zimbabwean government reserved the right to redistribute farms that were run by absentee owners, or that were left fallow for lengthy periods of time, or in cases where a single owner controlled multiple commercial farms. I don’t think that will necessarily reassure generals or party bigwigs, since many of them now own multiple former commercial farms that they leave largely fallow and on which they are absentee owners.

In any event, I don’t think it will be long before political scientists, economists and policy wonks outside of Zimbabwe start debating whether or not a public assurance to kleptocratic elites that they will be allowed to keep their ill-gotten gains sends the wrong incentive signals or creates a moral hazard or conversely, uses incentives properly to resolve an otherwise intractable situation. This is the same discussion that has been running for a while about whether genocide tribunals or other attempts to prosecute deposed dictators and military leaders for crimes against humanity help to discourage future incidents by promising that there will be consequences, or make authoritarians even more doggedly determined to hold onto power and more inclined to view all outside mediation as hostile or dangerous.

In the comments on a previous entry, Peter55 quite rightly wonders whether I really mean to be talking in this way about decision-making processes within Mugabe’s inner circle. I don’t mean to, because I largely dislike this entire conceptual framework. As Peter observes, it is frequently involves a misapplication of abstract models of human action and motivation to the real world. I find Freakonomics an interesting set of thought-experiments, but when we have to roll up our sleeves and deal with the fullness of human life as it is lived in any given time and place, we find that real people aren’t perfectly playing Prisoner’s Dilemma, aren’t weighing incentive structures, aren’t universal machines for maximizing utility, aren’t clearly running through the information available to them. They’re bound by the specificities of culture, by the inheritances of time, by limits of space, but also individuals can act in idiosyncratic, whimsical, creative or indeterminate ways. Models are an attempt to preemptively discount human unpredictability and invention and then to post-facto explain it as something which we always knew would happen anyway.

Perhaps even more importantly, however, I find the hubris of debates about whether or not this or that set of signals about incentives should be sent, or whether this or that action will have predictable futureward effects a kind of distasteful self-crowning by a transnational class of policy-makers and academic experts. When such a group sits down and asks, “Should we prosecute deposed dictators for their crimes against humanity in order to discourage future dictators, or should we avoid prosecuting them so as to give dictators incentives to leave office peacefully”, they’re imagining themselves as the philosopher-kings of a shadow state that is actually able to make those kinds of dispensations, actually able to calibrate incentives reliably. Sure, most of these kinds of experts will agree that we’re not there yet, but many see these kinds of conversations as the building blocks of that future global order.

So even if we understand people like Mugabe and his inner circle as calculating, incentive-evaluating, rational deciders, I think there is every reason for them to laugh behind closed doors at the hubris of the experts and activists, whatever the latest policy nostrum on tribunals, interventions, sanctions, golden parachutes or so on might be. Because what anyone outside of the rarified settings where generic 12-point plans for peacemaking and incentivizing prosecutions for genocide are composed knows is that every such action is and will be sui generis. The sand castles that the experts build today around one case will be washed away by the tides of history in short order. What happened in the end to Charles Taylor or Auguste Pinochet or Saddam Hussein or Slobodan Milosevic has little implication for tomorrow’s dictator and mass murderer. Because the people who play with constructing the machinery of incentive aspire to a kind of reliable managerial authority that they will never have, they are writing blank checks that no one will ever cash. Whether or not someone like Robert Mugabe dies peacefully in his bed, lives out his last years far from his home country, ends up in a pleasant prison while the United Nations dithers for a decade over his fate, is shot by an up-and-coming rival, or ends up torn to shreds by a mob is a matter of particular circumstance. That’s probably something most authoritarians know already, having ridden the vissitudes of history as far as they have.

Posted in Africa, Politics | 6 Comments

Contingency

The students in my Central Africa survey are writing papers about whether there were any distinct points at which the independence of the Belgian Congo might have turned out differently than it did. Like most counterfactuals involving colonialism, it’s a hard question to think through, partly because the general outcomes in postcolonial Central Africa (a weak and fractured state, corruption and autocracy, underdevelopment) don’t seem to turn intensely on the precise sequence of events in any given decolonization process.

Another problem is that it’s hard to confidently assess which decisions were considered by key actors that might also have seriously been pursued. It’s one thing to know that a conversation took place in which a whole range of options were discussed, and another thing to have to evaluate which ones might plausibly have been alternatives to the actual course pursued by various leaders and elites, and another thing still to decide which of those alternatives might have produced genuinely different outcomes.

These are the problems that we’re all confronted by as we watch Zimbabwe at this moment, with our breath held. It’s entirely plausible to imagine that in some guarded room in Harare, Mugabe and his inner circle, as well as key leaders from the police and military, have considered every scenario that observers can imagine: Mugabe leaving into exile, Mugabe resigning peacefully but remaining in Zimbabwe, stalling on any decision while a run-off is set-up, allowing a run-off but deciding to pull out all the stops to fix the outcome, declaring martial law or suspending the election results, rounding up Tsvangirai and the MDC leadership and imprisoning or killing them.

But we don’t know anything about how they might judge the plausibility of any of those scenarios, and we don’t know some of the information that would let us make those judgements ourselves. How much does Mugabe actually believe in his public self-image, and how surprising was the outcome to him? How anxious is the current leadership of the security apparatus and the ruling party about the threat of possible prosecutions under the MDC? How much force can they actually expect to command? Have African heads-of-state sent any private messages about consequences or the lack thereof from a crackdown?

Now, not knowing any of these things has never stopped outside experts from calling the odds as they see it. Personally, I think it’s looking increasingly plausible that ZANU and the security forces will stall for time by permitting a runoff while they decide whether to allow Mugabe to lose. (I’m pretty sure that by now, Mugabe is not personally able to dictate that outcome. He might not even be able to personally control whether or not to resign, if the security forces don’t want him to.) In my view, that would also allow the MDC to prepare for sustained popular protest if Tsvangirai is denied a victory in a runoff.

I could well be wrong: this is a guess that depends on a very distant set of inferences about the perceptions, motivations and resources of a set of actors who deliberately obscure information about all three of those aspects of their lives. Whenever something actually happens to resolve the uncertainty, the hard thing will be to remember that there was a point where that event, whatever it might be, didn’t seem inevitable.

Update: An ominous sign.

Posted in Africa | 8 Comments

Does the Other Shoe Ever Drop?

If you’ll recall, my initial statement on Ward Churchill was that I found his scholarly work extremely weak, and agreed that his case raised questions about standards and expectations in academic life, particularly in programs that see identity as a crucial source of scholarly or intellectual capital.

If the heart of the matter is standards, however, then the continuing work is to define what constitutes a minimum expectation for scholarly ability and performance, and to respond evenly to breaches of that expectation. Otherwise, complaints really are just “I don’t like or agree with Ward Churchill or [insert name here], ergo, throw the bum out”.

So riddle me this: why isn’t John Yoo just as big a hack when it comes to constitutional law as Ward Churchill was when it came to Native American history? This isn’t about simple disagreement with the substance of his arguments in the “torture memos”. It’s about Yoo making claims (claims with consequences far greater than what normally follows from scholarship, even legal scholarship) that are just factually wrong or are screamingly disingenuous.

Whatever the standards might be for employment at the Justice Department (a different issue), shouldn’t this kind of approach to knowledge and scholarship disqualify someone for an academic post?

Posted in Academia, Politics | 35 Comments

The Things That Hold

I spend a lot of time in my classes and my scholarly writing trying to explore the legacy of European colonialism and the Atlantic slave trade in Africa. I think these are wide-open questions. Depending on my mood, I can argue that the ongoing influence of that history is relatively minimal or that it is omnipresent and overwhelming.

When I have to commit to an argument, I tend to settle on a handful of practices and institutions that I think represent the most powerful and self-sustaining transformative effects of colonial government. Most of these I associate with the concept of “indirect rule”. In my view, some of the lasting impact has been lasting because of a fusion between local or indigenous practice and the colonial state. So, for example, the colonial state significantly transformed the political and institutional meaning of ethnic identity, but the substance of ethnic consciousness in many parts of the continent also drew significantly on precolonial political history in the 18th and 19th Centuries, on established languages and cultural repertoires, and so on. In contrast, the sillier or more delusional initiatives of colonial states faded quickly, or were wholly ignored from the outset by both imperial officers and local subjects.

I think we’re beginning to see the broad outlines of the longer-term impact of the U.S. presence in Iraq, whether the draw-down of U.S. forces starting in 2009 is relatively rapid or extremely prolonged. Some of the absurdities of the occupation before the surge will always be a good exhibit of folly and hubris for historians to investigate, but many of them have already proven ephemeral. On the other hand, the political accomodations that underlie the U.S. presence are, in my view, very much like the improvisational compacts and understandings between rural African elites and colonial bureaucrats that I believe formed the basis of British and French indirect rule in the early 20th Century in Africa. Shi’a, Sunni and Kurdish identity has been given new political meaning and new forms of expression within local, regional and national governance, and whatever happens next, I believe some of that change will have a lasting structural legacy. Partly as a consequence, interstate relations in the region are now fundamentally different, in ways which are arguably far more disadvantageous to U.S. interests than they were in 2001.

Another thing to consider is the physical landscape. Many African cities today are still profoundly structured and crippled by the common approach of European colonial rulers to urban development: reserve the central core of the city for administration and business, put a light manufacturing district near to the core, create a white or elite residential district not too far from the core, and put townships for African residence very far away from the core, separated from each other by large areas of vacant space and with little or no permanent infrastructure in order to discourage urbanization. Late in the colonial area, governments began to reverse these policies during the economic boom and rapid urbanization of the 1950s, but the physical layout was already set. The legacy of this approach to urbanization is serious: providing infrastructure, including transport, in many African cities combines the worst challenges of high-density urban development and suburban development in many other parts of the world.

In Iraq, perhaps the most lasting legacy of the surge may turn out to be the comprehensive reconstruction of the residential landscape of the major cities. It isn’t just that neighborhoods are now segregated by religious and ethnic identity, but that this segregation has been strongly reinforced by massive blast walls that allow military authorities to control and survey movement in and out of residential neighborhoods. This is going to be the idiom of urban life in Baghdad for decades to come, in all likelihood. Not one Berlin Wall, but many. It is hard to foresee the Iraqi state to come which will remove these walls, because they both express the new political reality of identity and because they are an available technology of control. In fact, should the Iraqi state become stronger rather than weaker in the future, it will probably see the walls as a more and more attractive method for maintaining its control, much as the isolation of many low-income, high-density neighborhoods from one another in much of urban Africa makes it easier for autocratic regimes to contain urban unrest, often a serious potential threat to the regime’s survival.

The United States bought itself and its client regime some political breathing space by control over violence during the surge, but the troop numbers on the ground only have been a small part of what has changed. The cost to Iraqis of that change is difficult to estimate because it involves changes whose full impact will likely not be clear for a long time to come. Much of the U.S. occupation may turn out to be ephemeral in many respects, remembered most potently by those who lost lives, health and sanity in its crucible. I think it’s important now to look past the surface incidents of violence and the debates about troop withdrawals to ask what kinds of structural transformations are taking hold, and whether any of them are still potentially malleable for good or ill.

Posted in Africa, Politics | 3 Comments

Gustatus Similus Pullus

You never know if you’re getting punk’d by a story on April Fool’s Day, but assuming this story about secret military units and their patches is on the level, there’s some interesting metacultural content to many of the patches. The Times is puzzled about the “Behind the Green Door” patch. All I can come up with is that the title refers to a 70s porn movie, but I don’t know what the green ghostly hand is stabbing with its dagger. Looks kind of like Black Manta from DC Comics. Actually, even if it’s a fake article, it’s very amusing.

Speaking of April Fool’s Day, if you’re at all interested in digital games, Blizzard Entertainment has outdone themselves this year with their April Fool’s content at the World of Warcraft site.

Posted in Miscellany | 5 Comments

March Out Like the Lion (In Zimbabwe, That Is)

I’ve been fielding a few requests for my evaluation of this weekend’s elections in Zimbabwe. There are scholars and journalists out there with more recent experience in Zimbabwe whose views I’d trust more than mine. Still, here’s how I laid it out in response to a query from a Brazilian journalist.

Q: Can the opposition win the election?

1) Can Morgan Tsvangirai gain a sufficiently strong majority of the vote that vote-rigging becomes implausibly difficult? If he only gets a small majority, I think it’s a given that the vote will be rigged in favor of Robert Mugabe. If he polls 60-65% or above, that becomes more difficult in technical terms. I don’t think Simba Makoni has a chance to poll a solid majority. Hence my second question:

2) Will Makoni and Tsvangirai split the vote to a meaningful extent? If they do, was that the intention all along?

I am not normally a conspiracy theorist, but Zimbabwean politics makes certain kinds of conspiracies plausible. One thing that Mugabe and his closest advisors have excelled at in the past thirty years, even before Zimbabwean independence, was pitting potential rivals against one another. The Zimbabwean intelligence service has also been involved in some deviously brilliant disinformation and covert action campaigns from time to time. So it is not entirely implausible that Makoni’s run was a deliberate strategy for splitting the vote and creating a credible scenario for Mugabe to win. At the very least, Mugabe and his inner circle can’t have overlooked the possible usefulness of his candidacy.

But it is also possible that Makoni represents a substantial if quiet faction of ZANU-PF that wants to substantially reform the government and try to competently manage the economy. In which case, the question is whether that faction can quietly or secretly mobilize sufficient support for him to have a solid plurality showing in the vote. Or whether they’re just putting Makoni forward to burnish his credentials as a reformer with the hope that he can be a compromise selection for president after a tainted election, or can help form a coalition between reform elements within ZANU-PF and the MDC if Tsvangarai wins.

3) If Tsvangirai wins a strong majority, will Mugabe stand down? I honestly don’t know, and I don’t think anyone else knows either. Certainly some of Mugabe’s loyalists in the police and military have hinted that they will not permit Tsvangirai to take power, but if comes to a showdown, I don’t think anyone knows whether Mugabe commands sufficient force or whether the military and police might split over the issue. This is one of the scenarios where I could imagine Makoni becoming President. If the military and police visibly split, or if they say they will not allow Tsvangarai to hold office, then it’s possible that mediators (probably South African) might argue for Makoni as a compromise candidate with strong MDC representation in his cabinet.

Q: Who still supports Mugabe?

The usual argument you will hear is that rural voters are strongly loyal to Mugabe. I actually don’t think that this is true, at least not as we usually understand party loyalty in liberal democracies. I think it is more that the Zimbabwean state is able to command and coerce rural citizens fairly effectively in terms of their formal interactions with the government, such as elections. In many districts, both chiefs and government officials (who are also ZANU-PF members) are able to order people to vote a particular way and have a reasonable expectation that their orders will be obeyed. The mechanisms of coercion range from fairly crude threats of violence to the dispersal of resources (including food) to those who toe the line. It’s very hard for the MDC or any other opposition to operate openly in most rural communities, so it is equally hard to gauge how much support they might have in a truly open political system.

That being said, ZANU-PF does have genuine loyalists in rural areas. The bedrock of the party’s support, however, comes from government officials, bureaucrats and others who are dependent upon the party’s largesse and are fearful of what might happen if control over the bureaucracy changes hands. The patron-client relations that ZANU-PF has honed to a fine edge have been the key to its grip on governmental power.

——–

Looking further ahead in my crystal ball, if Tsvangirai were to be recognized as the winner and actually took office, is he going to be able to reverse the dismal course of Zimbabwe’s history since 1997? Personally, I’m pessimistic, both because I think outsiders overestimate the degree to which Zimbabwe’s tailspin is all the consequence of Mugabe’s personal malice and incompetence. I think it has as much to do with the aging core leadership of ZANU-PF and a narrow slice of the upper bureaucracy. It will take more than an electoral victory to fix that problem. Something short of a revolution but beyond modest policy reforms. A reinvention of the Zimbabwean state, a reformation of the social ethics of the elite, a rejection of the nationalist imagination as it was defined in the 1970s. I think some of the people in the MDC see this wider canvas, but I’ve never really heard it clearly from Tsvangirai himself.

Still, anything would be a step up from Mugabe and his cronies. Hope springs eternal.

Posted in Africa | 6 Comments

Out of Pocket

Last night, I was searching through my iPod for some of the African music I’ve ripped from my CD collection, to play briefly in class today. Unfortunately, some of what we’ve got is on old vinyl records that I’ve never transferred into digital formats, and in particular a couple of albums by Franco.

So I took a whirl onto iTunes. I normally avoid buying from iTunes, but in this case, it was a quick, useful way to get two Franco tracks onto my iPod for class today. I could have spent only a fractionally greater amount of time and gone over to our music library to get the one Franco recording we have in our collection, though.

I was thinking about this a bit later, though: it made me think of all the times that I’ve bought things primarily for classroom use, sometimes to compensate for rushed or insufficient planning on my part. Books, mostly, but sometimes other media. I don’t really keep track of this, nor do I seek reimbursement. I’m kind of careless about that kind of thing in general: it’s part of my absent-minded professorhood.

However, I’m curious about whether this is totally aberrant behavior. You hear from time to time about K-12 teachers who buy supplies or materials for their classes, either because their own schools absolutely won’t or simply because it’s more convenient and doesn’t involve having to hassle with the bureaucracy for an oddball or idiosyncratic teaching plan.

Posted in Academia | 8 Comments

The Veil

Oso Raro and Tenured Radical underline one of the biggest problems with the tenure system in academia: its mystery.

They’re both trying to write about a controversial tenure case at the University of Michigan, to understand the seeming mismatch between the public transcript of the candidate’s accomplishments and the private decisions of the candidate’s colleagues. The problem is that there is no way to know about the second. A person who is denied tenure can go public with his or her reading, but the people involved in the denial can’t, regardless of whether they acted in good faith or not. Maybe there’s something we don’t know. Maybe there isn’t, and the public reading is all that we need to know that something went wrong. The uncertainty drives both outsiders and insiders mad with distraction. It makes it hard on the people being tenured or denied tenure: you want to go public, reveal, to say, “There is nothing unknown here, no private secret”.

The more you know about how tenure works as a system at your own institution, and at others, the less you can speak about its workings. I don’t feel I can talk in even heavily redacted terms about cases I’ve known directly (here and elsewhere) because that violates an essential commitment to confidentiality. The more cases you’ve seen in your own institution and throughout your discipline, the more you can imagine that there is something important about a given case that no outsider knows, but also the more you can imagine that something unfair happened in any given case.

The problem isn’t just mystery, though. It’s also mystification, the extent to which the parochial imagination of many academics leads them to believe that there is something different about the professoriate. In some ways, there is absolutely nothing unique about the confidentiality of the tenure system. When middle managers and professionals in other workplaces are fired, the same asymmetry of information applies. The person who is fired can choose to make a public stink about it, and that will circulate to the extent that the person is well-known in their profession or their community. The organization doing the firing often can’t say much about it for legal and professional reasons. By comparison, the tenure system is typically less arbitrary, more procedural, more knowable. If I were a vice-president at a bank–or even a senior administrator or adjunct faculty at a university–I could be terminated in much more unexpected, unfair or capricious fashion. You can object to the practice of firing people for anything but serious, documentable non-performance of their duties, but at that point, you’re really objecting philosophically to any labor market, objecting to termination as the whip hand of any kind of labor.

What makes tenure more fraught is not its secrecy, but its proceduralism. If I’m the bank vice-president, I can tell friends, colleagues and future employers that I was fired over a matter of principle, or by a boss whose ego was threatened, or because my bank was downsizing, or for other arbitrary reasons, and have all those narratives be perfectly credible. The existence of a lengthy dossier with evaluations from local colleagues, outside experts and students, a dossier evaluated in two or three or four separate confidential processes, seems to make the decision less arbitrary.

What makes tenure more fraught is also its consequences. There are a lot of banks and a lot of bank vice-presidencies, and a lot of other jobs that a bank vice-presidency might lead to. In some fields of academic study, there are perhaps no more than fifty to one hundred jobs total worldwide for which one might be qualified, many of them occupied by tenured faculty who can be expected to teach in those positions for the next two decades or more. For each open position, there will be many candidates, and anyone with a tenure denial on their record is at a disadvantage. Academics train for six or seven years, search for jobs for three or four years, teach for another six or seven, and then face the possibility of having to start over, in some cases with a near-total loss of the time invested in between. And that’s if you get lucky enough to get a tenure-track position in the first place, since the conditions of academic labor outside the tenure-track are exceptionally poor.

With or without tenure, however, confidentiality is still going to be an issue in academic life, as it is in all modern institutions. How do you document processes and decisions which by their nature cannot be documented? Motivations which remain unspoken, choices that happen by passive assent to an implicit narrative, secrets and silences: all institutions work by these processes as well as by public transcripts, transparent deliberations, honest actors.

Posted in Academia | 3 Comments

Border Guards

I was thinking of writing a One-a-Day post about Tim Weiner’s compelling history of the CIA, Legacy of Ashes. (I’ve been reading books, just not blogging about my reading. I’ll catch up soon.)

Then I read Stephen Weissman’s critique of the book at TPMCafe, and Weiner’s reply to Weissman.

If you read the sharp exchange between the two authors, you might be surprised at the mismatch of the tone to the substance. Weissman puts on an injured tone in replying to Weiner’s response to him, but take a look at his original post: he asks if Weiner’s book indicates that the standards for investigative reporting are slipping, he says that Weiner’s book contains “gross distortions”, says he is “shocked” by the mishandling of evidence. Weiner fires back with some very strong adjectives of his own, as well as an accusation that Weissman is carrying water for people inside the CIA.

What’s the substance? Primarily it’s about Weiner’s interpretation of a statement by Eisenhower that includes the phrase “legacy of ashes”. That’s what Weissman thinks is the “smoking gun” of gross distortion, that Weiner has made Eisenhower out to be a critic of the CIA when he really wasn’t. There’s a bigger disagreement in Weissman’s original post about whether the CIA has had some successes in covert action, but Weissman clearly recognizes that that particular argument is and will always remain a matter of interpretation, that it can’t be reduced to simple charges of inaccurate quotation.

This past week, I spent some time talking with students in my classes about the need to control their use of adverbs and adjectives so that they don’t get drawn into an implicit argument that they didn’t mean to make because of the intensity of their word choice. And yet here we have a scholar using words like “gross distortion” and “shocking”, a scholar who is criticizing another author on points of fine detail and calling for precision.

You can always tell when a serious scholarly pissing match is about to kick off in a journal or a listserv or a conference panel: it’s exactly when you see this mismatch between the intensity of the adjectives used by one scholar to describe his opponent and the alleged errors being described. Reading the exchange between Weissman and Weiner, I’m almost convinced that Weissmann is right that Weiner is bending the Eisenhower quote a bit, though once things get to this intensity of disagreement, I don’t blindly trust anyone’s representation of the source material. But it’s not much of a bending, really, and it amounts to next to nothing compared to the book as a whole. If this is what Weissman has to lead with in making a claim of “gross distortion”, the case for the prosecution is really weak. The book as a whole is strongly researched, compellingly written and forcefully argued. Getting caught up on a handful of quotes is petty.

The real challenge, if Weissman disagrees about the overall argument, is to deal with the overall argument not in terms of inaccuracy and accuracy but in philosophical terms. Weissman believes as a matter of principle that covert action (as opposed to intelligence gathering) is possible, and that the CIA has succeeded at times with covert action. Weiner, if I read him right, is fundamentally skeptical about covert action. That’s not a disagreement that’s easily resolved on the facts: it runs far deeper.

Another example of where the disagreement ought to be more collegial and subtle: Weissman is right that Weiner isn’t much interested in the technological improvement of intelligence in the last fifty years. As I read Weiner’s book, that’s partly because he thinks the intelligence-gathering work of the CIA doesn’t pose a philosophical problem, just a technical one, and that the real issue is with human intelligence and analysis, with the interpretation of the intention and interior deliberations of other governments, or with subjective readings of the state of other societies. It is up to Weissman to argue about why signals intelligence compensates for those problems if he feels that Weiner’s lack of interest in intelligence technology is a major issue. That’s an interesting disagreement, the kind of rising tide that floats all boats.

If this was a case of two scholars working in a field who basically had a friendly relationship, the kind of points that Weissman makes about Weiner’s work could be tossed off in a genial, collegial manner, even if there were some sharp needles buried underneath the cottony surface. Most of the time this is what happens in debates between colleagues who see themselves as part of the same field.

When you see this kind of adjectival intensity associated with such a relatively picayune point, one of two things is going on. One possibility is that there is a major analytic disagreement about the overall substance of a book, and both parties to that disagreement represent substantial schools of thought or factions with a long-running history of antagonism. I think that’s partly the case here.

Or the critic whose tone is mismatched to substance is a gatekeeper: someone accustomed to personal ownership of a given subject, to disciplinary ownership of a subject, or who is trying to keep non-academics off of turf perceived to be a scholarly monopoly. (Sometimes it’s as simple as one scholar who was planning to work on a subject trying to ruin the market value of a competitor’s work.) I think that’s part of what is going on in this exchange: Weiner’s being painted as a trespasser.

Gatekeeping happens a lot in academia, and it’s yet another reason that other professionals sometimes resent the professoriate. Generosity really does seem to me to be the best policy as a matter of professional ethos for scholars, for a whole host of reasons. If we really believe in knowledge production, we’re obligated to be generous and welcoming, and to try and disagree about the main substance of rivalrous works.

Gatekeeping often achieves its goals, however. I know that reading this exchange makes me feel very uncomfortable about what lies ahead for me in my next project, which is a general history of Africa in the Cold War. I’m especially interested in the history of intelligence, and Weissman’s book A Culture of Deference has already been a very valuable, interesting source for me. I’m very conscious that I’m an outsider moving into a heavily inhabited area of specialization. I’m hoping that’s the value I add to the subject, as a cultural and social historian whose usual methodology is wholly qualitative. Anyone who has been around academia long enough, however, knows what is likely to follow when an outsider moves into new territory which is heavily patrolled by intensely protective gatekeepers. Archives can be difficult to access, funding can be hard to come by, anonymous peer reviews will be brutal, and there are inevitably going to be conference panels in the future where bruising attacks will come from the floor. That is enough in many cases to deter scholars from crossing borders, to encourage them to stick to their own social networks and areas of established expertise.

Posted in Academia, Africa, Books | 1 Comment